New - Welcome to the 2025 website! Please note we are currently updating it and information may not be up-to-date yet.

M11 Ruin probability and reinsurance

Topics in Insurance, Risk, and Finance

Author
Affiliation

Yuyu Chen

Department of Economics, University of Melbourne

Published

2024

Adjustment Coefficient and Lundberg’s inequality

Ruin probability for exponential claims

Example: exponential claims

Suppose X1,X2, follow an exponential distribution F(x)=1eαx for x0 and c=(1+θ)λm1. What is ψ(u)?

We have ψ(u)=ψ(0)exp(Ru)=λαcexp((αλ/c)u)=11+θexp(αθu1+θ). Hence, the ultimate ruin probability is independent of the Poisson parameter λ.

Lundberg’s inequality

As in the discrete time risk model, an upper bound also exists for the ultimate ruin probability in the classical risk model.

  • If c=(1+θ)λm1, the above equation reduces to MX(R)=1+(1+θ)m1R, so that R is independent of the Poisson parameter λ.

Additional comments

  • For large initial surplus u, the ultimate ruin probability is close to the upper bound. Hence, we have the approximation ψ(u)exp(Ru), which is often used in actuarial literature.
  • Clearly, the upper bound exp(Ru) decreases as R increases, where exp(Ru) is used as an approximation of ψ(u). Arguably, the ultimate ruin probability ψ(u) also decreases as R increases.
  • By the second bullet point, we can regard the adjustment coefficient R as a (reverse) measure of risk for insurers: The larger R is, the less risk insurers face.
  • eR can be regarded as the factor by which the ruin probability decreases given a unit increase in the initial surplus.

Proof of Lundberg’s inequality I

  • Let ψn(u), n=1,2,, be the probability that ruin happens before nth claim.
  • Note that limnψn(u)=ψ(u) and ψn(u) increases as n increases.
  • Hence it suffices to show ψn(u)exp(Ru) for all n=1,2,. This is done by induction.

Proof of Lundberg’s inequality II

Assuming that ψn(u)exp(Ru), we show that ψn+1(u)exp(Ru) holds.

ψn+1(u)=0λexp(λt)u+ctf(x)dxdt+0λexp(λt)0u+ctψn(u+ctx)f(x)dxdt0λexp(λt)u+ctf(x)dxdt+0λexp(λt)0u+ctexp(R(u+ctx))f(x)dxdt0λexp(λt)0exp(R(u+ctx))f(x)dxdt=exp(Ru). The last equality uses the fact that λMX(R)=λ+cR.

Proof of Lundberg’s inequality III

The rest is to show ψ1(u)exp(Ru). We have ψ1(u)=0λeλtu+ctf(x)dxdt0λeλtu+ctf(x)exp(R(u+ctx))dxdt0λeλt0f(x)exp(R(u+ctx))dxdt=exp(Ru). The proof is done.

Uniqueness of the root I

To show λMX(R)λcR=0 has a unique root, we need the assumption that for some γ, MX(r) is finite for all r<γ and limrγMX(r)=.

Define g(r)=λMX(r)λcr. Note that g(0)=0. We first show limrγg(r)=.

For γ<, it is obvious.

Uniqueness of the root II

For γ=, note there exists ϵ>0 such that MX(r)=0erxf(x)dxϵerxf(x)dxϵerϵf(x)dx=erϵP(Xϵ).

Hence, limrγg(r)limrγ(λerϵP(Xϵ)λcr)=

Uniqueness of the root III

Take derivatives of g(r). We get ddrg(r)=λddrMX(r)c. Hence, ddrg(r)|r=0=λm1c<0. Also d2dr2g(r)=λd2dr2MX(r)>0. Consequently, g(r) is a convex function with g(0)=0 and limrγg(r)=. The desired result is obtained.

Example: exponential losses I

If the individual claims follow the exponential distribution F(x)=1exp(αx) for x0, then MX(r)=α/(αr) for r<α. Hence, we need to solve λMX(R)=λααR=λ+cR, which is equivalent to cR2+(λαc)R=0. Hence, R=αλ/c.

Example: exponential losses II

If we write c=(1+θ)λm1=(1+θ)λ/α, we have R=αλc=θα1+θ. Since dRdθ=α(1+θ2)>0,

  • We can see that as θ increases, R increases, and essentially exp(Ru) decreases which is the upper bound of ψ(u).
  • That makes sense as we are charging more premium at a higher θ.
  • We obtained an explicit solution in the above example. In most cases, however, R can only be solved numerically.

Example: mixtures of exponential distributions I

If the individual claims follow the distribution F(x)=10.5(exp(3x)+exp(7x)), for x0, find R when λ=3 and c=1.

Example: mixtures of exponential distributions II

The moment generating function of individual claim is MX(r)=0.5(33r+77r).

Note that MX(r) exists for r<3.Hence, by λ+cR=λMX(R), we get R37R2+6R=R(R1)(R6)=0, which gives R=1.

An upper bound of adjustment coefficient

  • If R is small, this upper bound can a good approximation of R.
  • If c=(1+θ)λm1, we get R<2θm1/m2.

An upper bound of adjustment coefficient: proof

We have exp(x)=1+x+x22+o(x)>1+x+x22. Hence we have λ+cR=λMX(R)=λ\E(exp(RX))=λ\E(1+RX+(RX)22+o(RX))>λ\E(1+RX+(RX)22)=λ(1+Rm1+R22m2).

Solving the above inequality, we get the desired result.

Example: mixtures of exponential distributions (upper bound of R)

If the individual claims follow the exponential distribution F(x)=10.5(exp(3x)exp(7x)) for x0, we have seen that R=1 when λ=3 and c=1.

We have m1=0.5(13+17)=521, and m2=0.5(232+272)=58441, The upper bound is R<2(cλm1)λm2=1.45, which is not close to the true value.

A lower bound of adjustment coefficient

Hence if each individual claim has an upper bound, we can also derive a lower bound for R.

A lower bound of adjustment coefficient: proof

Assume that XM where M>0. We first show for 0xM: exp(Rx)xMexp(RM)+1xM. We have xMexp(RM)+1xM=xMj=0(RM)jj!+1xM=1+j=1RjMj1xj!1+j=1(Rx)jj!=exp(Rx).

A lower bound of adjustment coefficient: proof

We have λ+cR=λMX(R)=λ0exp(Rx)f(x)dxλ0(xMexp(RM)+1xM)f(x)dx=λMexp(RM)m1+λλMm1. Then cλm11RM(exp(RM)1)=1+RM2!+(RM)23!+1+RM1!+(RM)22!+=exp(RM). Hence R>1Mlog(cλm1).

Ruin probabilities against changing parameters

Ruin probabilities

Recall that in the classical risk process, continuous-time ruin probabilities are defined as ψ(u)=P(T<), and ψ(u,t)=P(T<t). where T=min{t>0:U(t)<0} is the first time of ruin.

Ruin probabilities against t

For 0<t1t2<, and u0, ψ(u,t1)ψ(u,t2)ψ(u). This is clear as {T<t1}{T<t2}{T<}. Hence ψ(u,t) is an increasing function of t.

Ruin probabilities against u

For 0u1u2, ψ(u1)ψ(u2). This is because ψ(u)=\p(u+ctS(t)<0  for some  t>0) and that {u2+ctS(t)<0  for some  t>0}{u1+ctS(t)<0  for some  t>0} Hence, ψ(u) is a decreasing function of u. Similarly, we have ψ(u1,t)ψ(u2,t).

Ruin probabilities against θ

  • Probabilities ψ(u) and ψ(u,t) are both decreasing against θ.
  • This is intuitively true as a larger θ means more premium income.
  • One can also prove this result using similar arguments for the previous result regarding ruin probabilities against u.

Reinsurance and expected utility

Decision models

  • Recall that for an agent/decision maker with utility function u and wealth random variable X, the agent’s goal is to maximize \E(u(X)).
  • The agent is risk-averse if its utility function is increasing and concave.
  • Risk aversion means: (a) the more wealth the better
  1. the marginal utility is decreasing.
  • We will study how reinsurance can affect an insurer’s decision making, i.e., how to make the optimal decision in the presence of reinsurance.
  • One can also use risk measures like VaR to measure the agent’s risk (although not covered in this subject).

Reinsurance

  • Insurers pay premiums to reinsurers to transfer part of their losses.
  • Reinsurance reduces the variability of the aggregate claims so that the probability of ruin can be reduced.
  • A reinsurance contract is said to be optimal if the insurer’s utility is maximized or the probability of ruin is minimized.

Two types of reinsurance: proportion reinsurance

Proportion reinsurance: the reinsurer covers a prespecified proportion of each risk in the portfolio and the reinsurance premium is in proportion to the risk ceded.

If the insurer has a retained proportion α, then when a loss X occurs, the insurer will need to pay αX and the reinsurer will pay (1α)X.

Two types of reinsurance: excess of loss reinsurance

Excess of loss reinsurance: the reinsurer pays the claim which is beyond a prespecified limit. In other words, the insurer’s liability is capped. The cap is referred to as the retention of the insurer.

If the insurer has a retention limit M, then when a loss X occurs, the insurer will need to pay min(X,M) and the reinsurer will pay max(XM,0).

Application of utility theory I

Throughout this section, we make the following assumptions:

  • The insurer uses the exponential utility function: u(x)=exp(βx), where β>0. This implies that the insurer is risk-averse.
  • The insurer’s claim number follows a Poisson distribution with Poisson parameter λ and the individual claim distribution is F with density f and F(0)=0. This means that the aggregate claim follows a compound Poisson distribution.
  • Note that this is not the classical risk model.

Application of utility theory II

Suppose that the insurer with policies is considering buying reinsurance. The insurer has wealth at the end of a period: WI=W+PPRSI, where

  • W is the insurer’s wealth at the start of the period
  • P is the premium the insurer receives to cover the risk
  • PR is the amount of the reinsurance premium
  • SI denotes the amount of claims paid by the insurer net of reinsurance

Application of utility theory III

The goal is to maximize the expected utility of the insurer: max\E[u(WI)]=max\E[u(W+PPRSI)]=maxexp(β(W+P))(exp(βPR))\E[exp(βSI)]. Since W and P are constant, the above problem is equivalent to: max(exp(βPR))\E[exp(βSI)]. We need to decide PR and SI such that the above expression can be maximized.

Two premium principles

  • The expected value principle sets the premium of a claim X as PX=(1+θ)\E[X], where θ>0 is the premium loading factor.
  • For a utility function u and an insurer with initial wealth W, premium PX and a claim X, the principle of Zero utility sets the premium by the following equality: u(W)=\E[u(W+PXX)]. In the case of exponential utility u(x)=exp(βx) (called the exponential principle), we have PX=log\E[exp(βX)]β=logMX(β)β.

Application of utility: proportional reinsurance I

Assumes the reinsurer covers 1α of each claim and the reinsurance premium is calculated by the exponential principle with parameter A.

The reinsurance premium is thus PR=λA(0e(1α)Axf(x)dx1), and \E[exp(βSI)]=exp(λ(0eαβxf(x)dx1)).

Application of utility: proportional reinsurance II

Therefore, we are to maximize exp(βPR)\E[exp(βSI)]=exp(λβA(0e(1α)Axf(x)dx1)+λ(0eαβxf(x)dx1)), which is equivalent to minimize h(α)=λβA0e(1α)Axf(x)dx+λ0eαβxf(x)dx=λ0(A1βe(1α)Ax+eαβx)f(x)dx.

Application of utility: proportional reinsurance III

Taking derivatives of h(α), we get ddαh(α)=λ0(xβe(1α)Ax+βxeαβx)f(x)dx, and d2dα2h(α)=λ0(Ax2βe(1α)Ax+β2x2eαβx)f(x)dx>0. Hence, h(α) has a minimum at α=A/(A+β).

Application of utility: excess of loss reinsurance I

Let us now assume that the insurer effects excess of loss reinsurance with retention level M and that the reinsurance premium is calculated by the expected value principle with loading θ. The reinsurance premium is thus PR=(1+θ)λM(xM)f(x)dx, and that E[exp(βSI)]=exp(λ(0Meβxf(x)dx+eβM(1F(M))1)).

Application of utility: excess of loss reinsurance II

We are to maximize exp(βPR)\E[exp(βSI)]. Equivalently, we are to minimize

g(M)=(1+θ)λβM(xM)f(x)dx+λ(0Meβxf(x)dx+eβM(1F(M))).

Taking derivatives of g(M), we have ddMg(M)=(1+θ)λβ(F(M)1)+λβeβM(1F(M))=λβ(1F(M))(eβM1θ), which equals to 0 when M=log(1+θ)/β. Since the second derivative of g(M) is positive at log(1+θ)/β, we found the minimum of g(M).

Example: excess of loss reinsurance

Aggregate claims from a risk have a compound Poisson distribution with Poisson parameter 100, and individual claim amounts are exponentially distributed with mean 100. The insurer of this risk decides to effect excess of loss reinsurance, and the reinsurance premium is calculated according to the variance principle with parameter 0.5 (i.e., for a random loss X, the premium is \E(X)+0.5\var(X)). Find the retention level that maximizes the insurer’s expected utility of wealth with respect to the utility function u(x)=exp(0.005x).

Example: excess of loss reinsurance

  • Let Xi be the ith claim after reinsurance.
  • Let Y1,Y2, be the losses of the reinsurer.
  • We want to maximize \E(u(W+PPRi=1NXi)).
  • Essentially, we need to maximize \E(u(PRi=1NXi))=exp(βPR)\E(exp(βi=1NXi)).

Example: excess of loss reinsurance

We have PR=\E(i=1NYi)+0.5\var(i=1NYi)=100\E(Yi)+0.5100\E(Yi2). Denote by M the retention level. We have \E(Yi)=100e0.01M, and \E(Yi2)=20000e0.01M. Then PR=1010000e0.01M.

Example: excess of loss reinsurance

In this question, β=0.005. Then \E(exp(βi=1NXi))=exp(100(1e0.005M)).

Example: excess of loss reinsurance

We are then to maximize exp(βPR)\E(exp(βi=1NXi))=exp(β1010000e0.01M+100(1e0.005M)). Let h(M)=5050e0.01M+100(1e0.005M). Then h(M)=50.5e0.01M+0.5e0.005M. The optimal retention level is M=200(log101). Second derivative is positive at this point.

Back to top